BEFORE THE
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
Washington, D.C. 20554
In the Matter of )
)
Access Charge Reform ) CC DOC 96-262
)
Price Cap Performance Review ) CC Docket No. 94-1
for Local Exchange Carriers )
)
Transport Rate Structure ) CC Docket No. 91-213
and Pricing )
)
Usage of the Public Switched ) CC Docket No. 96-263
Network by Information Service )
and Internet Access Providers )
COMMENTS
of the
RURAL TELEPHONE COALITION
January 29, 1997
TABLE OF CONTENTS
PAGE
SUMMARY iii
I. ACCESS REFORM IS NEEDED FOR BOTH PRICE CAP AND RATE OF RETURN
INCUMBENT LECS. 1
A. Decisions Regarding Access Reform for Price Cap LECs will Likely Dictate
Subsequent Reforms for Rate of Return LECs. 1
B. Continuation of Rate Structure Regulation, A Recent Phenomenon, Is No Longer
Justifiable. 4
II. FLAT RATE CARRIER COMMON LINE CHARGES TO IXCS MAKE ECONOMIC
SENSE. 6
A. Eliminating The SLC Cap On Additional Lines Will Be Devastating To Rural
Economies And Is Unlawful. 7
B. The RTC Supports Flat Charges For The NTS Portion of Local Switching Costs,
Provided The Actual Costs Are Properly Identified 9
C. Transport Costs Should Be Properly Identified And Shifted To The Correct
Elements. 10
III. TRANSITION ISSUES 13
A. Universal Service 13
B. Embedded costs 14
C. The Commission Must Adopt A Mechanism To Permit Small LEC Recovery Of
Costs Incurred In Response To A Federal And State Commission-Supervised
Regulatory Scheme. 15
IV. "REFORMED" ACCESS CHARGE RULES SHOULD AVOID UNJUSTIFIED
DISCRIMINATION AND PREFERENCES, BENEFIT END USERS AND COMPLY
WITH THE NEW LAW'S UNIVERSAL SERVICE PROVISIONS. 22
A. Terminating Access Treatment Should Be The Same For Incumbents And Their
Competitors And Consistent With Fostering Efficient Use Of Telecommunications
Services. 22
1. There Is No Justification For Discriminating Between ILECS And LECS
In Regulating Terminating Access. 22
2. The Commission Should Not Discourage Efficient Use Of The Network
By Charging The Called Party For Terminating Access. 24
B. The Commission Should Require Interexchange Carriers To Pass All Access
Charge Reductions Through To Their End Users. 26
C. The Commission Cannot Justify Forbearing From Enforcing The Act's Geographic
Interexchange Rate Averaging Requirement Rather Than Providing "Sufficient"
Universal Service Support To Make The Policy Work. 27
V. THE COMMISSION MUST PERFORM A REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY
ANALYSIS AND CONSIDER HOW ITS DECISION WILL AFFECT THE
ECONOMIC INTERESTS OF SMALL INCUMBENT LECS. 32
CONCLUSION 36
SUMMARY
For small LECs, access reform is as important as it is to price cap companies. Principles underlying rules established for price cap LECs must be consistent with principles underlying rules for small LECs. The Commission should return to the "carrier initiated rates" methodology. The LECs are in the best position to design their own rate structures that reflect their own circumstances. This change would not require the Commission to give up its authority to set rate levels.
RTC agrees with the Commission that flat rate carrier common line charges to IXCs make economic sense. NTS costs associated with the CCL charge should not be recovered on a traffic sensitive basis. Although the RTC supports a flat rate charge, it believes the most efficient way to recover these costs is by bulk billing the IXCs that are the cost causers. Increase of the SLC on second lines is an unwise choice as it defeats the universal service goals of the Act. A great proportion of rural companies' switching costs are nontraffic sensitive. The Commission should recognize this fact in the course of its examination of NTS costs associated with switching.
As the revenue streams associated with the TIC are vitally important to rural companies,
the RTC urges the Commission to base its revised rules on data that adequately reflect the costs
associated with rural company provision of transport. The RTC believes that transport costs can
be made explicit and bulk billed to the IXCs. Whatever recovery the Commission devises should
take account of the higher costs of providing transport in low density rural areas.
The Commission should resolve its terminating access charge concerns the same way for incumbent LECs and CLECs because the differences between originating and terminating access, such as whose customer chooses the local distribution carrier, are the same for both types of LECs. Reluctance to impose regulation on competitive entrants and eagerness to retain regulation for incumbents are not legally sufficient reasons for treating similarly-circumstanced LECs disparately. The chosen approach should employ minimal regulation, but should not (a) transfer all recovery for terminating access to the originating caller without adopting universal service mechanisms that will maintain interexchange rate averaging and rural long distance competition incentives, or (b) discourage call acceptance by charging the called party.
Another measure necessary to prevent interexchange carriers from absorbing any access
charge reductions in profits is a requirement to pass such reductions through proportionately to
interexchange carriers' end users. The marketplace evidence related to interexchange price
changes indicates that interexchange competition has not yet driven prices to each carrier's
forward looking costs. Moreover, the Commission should not forbear from enforcing the recently
adopted statutory requirement for interexchange rate averaging to allow deaveraged flat customer
charges by interexchange carriers, effectively creating a second SLC. There is no basis for finding
that the policy is no longer necessary to maintain average rates and protect customers and
Congress would not have enacted the mandate if it thought there was no need. The Commission
should adopt effective universal service support for interexchange averaging if it allows or
requires access charge deaveraging that will further unstabilize incentives to average
interexchange rates in accordance with the law.
The Commission should also consider a mechanism that will permit incumbents, particularly small ILECs to recover stranded investment costs associated with the transition to a competitive environment. Specific mechanisms are required to prevent confiscation. Under the prior regulatory regime, the ILECs maintained adequate facilities and invested in state of the art technologies to fulfill carrier of last resort obligations imposed on them by federal and state mandates. Today, the same federal and state authorities that required these investments are promoting a new regime that may result in the ILECs inability to recover prudent investments.
Lastly, the Commission is required to perform a Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) Analysis since the rules it adopts will affect more than half of the revenues of small LECs that are "small entities" under applicable the RFA and Small Business Administration regulations.
BEFORE THE
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
Washington, D.C. 20554
In the Matter of )
)
Access Charge Reform ) CC DOC 96-262
)
Price Cap Performance Review ) CC Docket No. 94-1
for Local Exchange Carriers )
)
Transport Rate Structure ) CC Docket No. 91-213
and Pricing )
)
Usage of the Public Switched ) CC Docket No. 96-263
Network by Information Service )
and Internet Access Providers )
COMMENTS OF
THE RURAL TELEPHONE COALITION
The Rural Telephone Coalition (RTC) hereby files its comments in response to the Commission's Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) released December 24, l996, FCC 96-488. The RTC is comprised of the National Rural Telecom Association (NRTA), the National Telephone Cooperative Association (NTCA), and the Organization for the Promotion and Advancement of Small Telecommunications Companies (OPASTCO).
I. ACCESS REFORM IS NEEDED FOR BOTH PRICE CAP AND RATE OF
RETURN INCUMBENT LECS.
A. Decisions Regarding Access Reform for Price Cap LECs will Likely Dictate
Subsequent Reforms for Rate of Return LECs.
The reforms to the Part 69 access charge structure rules proposed by the NPRM are intended by the Commission to eliminate inefficiencies in those rules and produce a structure that would be produced by a competitive market.(1) The Commission correctly states that there is a broad consensus in favor of access reform.(2) Indeed, the RTC has made reference to the necessity of reform, and coordination with other proceedings, several times in recent years.(3) Believing that the need for access reform is most immediate for Price Cap regulated LECs because they are likely to face significant competition in the interstate exchange access market from new entrants using unbundled elements, the Commission concludes that it should focus first, with some exceptions, on revising Part 69 only for Price Cap LECs and initiating a separate proceeding for rate of return regulated LECs.
The RTC believes this focus is misplaced and that all aspects of this proceeding must also consider the situation of rate of return LECs. The Commission is probably correct that most of the initial competition through unbundled elements will occur in areas served by the larger LECs. This is to be expected not because they are regulated by price caps, but because they tend to serve the more urban markets with higher densities and lower costs which are attractive to new entrants. This would be the situation if there were no price cap regulation, or all LECs were on price caps. Further, some rate of return LECs can also expect to be subject to providing unbundled elements, and for these the need for relief from a rate structure dictated by the Commission in l984 is just as urgent(4)
. In any event, the need for reform goes well beyond the need to respond to competitors' purchase of unbundled elements. For example, as the NPRM notes, ". . . the access rules create incentives for IXCs to bypass the LEC switched access network for reasons that have nothing to do with the economics of operating an access network."(5) Other examples include per minute access charges that exceed the economic cost of providing service to some customers,(6) and assignment of costs to the wrong elements.
Price cap regulation is not, therefore, a valid indicator of the degree of need of access reform. All incumbent LECs are affected to some degree by the new environment, many aspects of which preceded the 1996 Act. The Commission's statement that rates should reflect the manner in which costs are incurred is no less applicable to rural than to urban LECs.(7) The real question is how best to achieve that goal.
Even to the extent that the need may be more urgent for some LECs than others, the Commission should not further "atomize" its implementation of the 1996 Act. If the goal is to achieve rate structures which reflect the way costs are incurred, then the only logical division is between LECs which incur costs differently in some material way, or between those subject to different degrees of competition. But even if such divisions could be identified, rule making here that deliberately ignored rate of return LECs' circumstances would prejudge and prejudice their later rulemaking because the principles established for one must be consistent with the other. If, however, the Commission purports to defer all rate of return issues for later consideration, it will without doubt reach decisions in the first proceeding, dealing with large LECs, which will then be applied to rural LECs.
B. Continuation of Rate Structure Regulation, A Recent Phenomenon, Is No
Longer Justifiable.
For the first fifty years of its existence, the Commission left questions of rate structure design to carrier initiative, subject to tariff review under the just, reasonable and non-discriminatory standards of Section 201(b) and 202(a) of the 1934 Act. The current Part 69 rules had their genesis, as the NPRM notes, in the 1979 ENFIA agreement.(8) A major issue resolved in that agreement was the responsibility of an interexchange carrier to compensate a LEC for use of its facilities for the origination and termination of interstate traffic. The resolution of that issue involved very specific agreements as to what elements would receive compensation and at what level, and these specifications evolved over a five year period into the Part 69 structure.(9)
From the beginning, it was clear that some Part 69 rate elements simply did not work and had to be granted permanent waivers. Today, the industry is much more complex and changing at a more rapid rate, yet the Commission persists in the view that, in a rule making proceeding, it can prescribe detailed elements which will "reflect the manner in which costs are incurred."(10) The very discussion in the NPRM of the failings of the current rules in this regard should alert the Commission to the essential impossibility of reasonably approximating this goal. First, for any given LEC at a given point in time, it is very difficult to determine exactly how costs are incurred. Any subdivision of any entity's costs, whether embedded or forward looking, necessarily requires arbitrary allocations and conventions that, at best, oversimplify complex, dynamic phenomena. Even if a close enough approximation can be developed for that LEC, it is not likely to fit well for other LECs which operate under different market, regulatory and demographic conditions, using technology from different vendors. Further, even assuming reasonable accuracy at the time of closing of the record in a rule making, the facts will certainly change in a much shorter interval than the period between effective revisions of the FCC rules.
The Commission should, therefore, at least begin the process of returning regulation of all LECs to the "carrier initiated rates" methodology contemplated by the 1934 Act, without regard to whether the LECs are price cap or rate of return, or subject to Section 251(c) or not. This is not to say that all immediate steps, as proposed in the NPRM should be deferred. Many of these have merit and general support within the industry.
At the same time, however, the Commission should move toward returning to LECs the initiative to design their own appropriate rate structures, since they are in the best position to understand, and revise as appropriate, a structure which best reflects their circumstances. Such regulatory change would recognize the impossibility of accurately predicting structure issues for an entire industry, would be more consistent with the competitive environment, and would make errors the responsibility of the LECs, rather than the Commission. Such a change would not reduce the Commission's authority to set rate levels or to find, in the case of any particular tariff, that the rate structure is inconsistent with the Act.
The RTC proposal, above, is consistent with, but separate from, the NPRM's alternative proposal to use a "market approach" for access reform and inconsistent with the prescriptive approach. For most rate of return carriers the competition they immediately face is not unbundled element competition, but other forms, including that from wireless carriers and bypass by IXCs, and this competition has been developing over many years. The conditions proposed to be imposed on the price cap LECs are therefore unnecessary for rate of return LECs and should not be imposed on them as a cost of moving toward a more rational rate structure.
II. FLAT RATE CARRIER COMMON LINE CHARGES TO IXCS MAKE
ECONOMIC SENSE.
As the Commission streamlines regulations and allows markets to work, its suggestion
that "it would be preferable for costs related to the loop to be recovered in a manner that is
consistent with the manner in which the costs are incurred"(11) makes economic sense. The RTC
agrees with the latter principle and believes that non-traffic sensitive (NTS) costs associated with
the carrier common line (CCL) charge should not be recovered on a traffic sensitive basis. The
RTC urges the Commission to bear efficient market principles in mind as it develops cost
recovery mechanisms in its proposed structure modifications.
Either a flat rate or bulk billed CCL mechanism will properly reflect cost causation principles. Basing CCL recovery on pre-subscribed lines would work and is the most administratively simple mechanism. A cost recovery system that uses interexchange carriers' (IXCs) percentage of revenue would address the Commission's concern about "dialing-around"(12) the pre-subscribed interexchange carrier (PIC). A flat rate, NTS CCL charge is one proposal that could be "extended to rate-of-return LECs."(13) However, the proposal to "allow incumbent LECs to collect the flat rate charge that would otherwise be assessed against the PIC directly from any customer"(14) would unnecessarily transfer the collection of costs caused by interexchange service to LECs and their customers. Bulk billing the IXC cost causers and allowing them to pass the cost through to their end users consistent with the section 254(g) prohibition on deaveraged interexchange charges, is the most efficient and justifiable solution.
A. Eliminating The SLC Cap On Additional Lines Will Be Devastating To
Rural Economies And Is Unlawful.
The Commission's ill-advised proposal to eliminate or increase the subscriber line charge (SLC) cap on second lines, second residences, and multiline businesses,(15) coupled with the proposed loss of high cost support,(16) would have devastating effects on "access to advanced services,"(17) promotion of second lines, and development of fragile rural economies. Accordingly, "any changes [the Commission] adopts to the cap on SLCs"(18) should not be extended to rate-of-return LECs. The Act mandates that "[a]ccess to advanced telecommunications and information services should be provided to all regions of the nation."(19) The Commission's prejudice against second lines will make the cost of additional lines for faxes or internet access out of reach in rural areas with high costs of service. Rural citizens already have to travel long distances to reach their schools and libraries. A second line at home makes the education opportunities available on the internet a realistic possibility for remote rural citizens. The Commission's proposal to abandon additional lines, ironically would abandon its demonstrated commitment to education. Conceivably, a rural subscriber or multiline rural business customer will have to pay not only the actual cost of the additional lines (due to the elimination of high cost support), but also an increased SLC. This latest proposal adds insult to the injury of losing high cost support. Measured by any public interest standard, increased SLCs on additional lines are clearly detrimental to rural economies.
Additionally, the proposal to increase the SLC cap is inconsistent with Section 254 of the Act. Specifically, the statute mandates that:
consumers in all regions of the nation, including low-income consumers and those
in rural, insular, and high cost areas, should have access to telecommunications and
information services, including interexchange services and advanced
telecommunications and information services, that are reasonably comparable to
those services provided in urban areas and that are available at rates that are
reasonably comparable to rates charged for similar services in urban areas(20)
The Commission cannot simply ignore the urban/rural comparability commitment of the Act. An increased SLC is the antithesis of comparable access to "interexchange services".(21) Small rural businesses and rural subscribers desiring a connection to the information age might not be able to afford additional lines. Also, they will be paying more or an unfair share of the costs for interconnection to the interexchange network. The only entities that will benefit from such a skewed system will be the IXCs that will garner toll charges without having to pay their share of the costs involved in accessing the local network.
B. The RTC Supports Flat Charges For The NTS Portion of Local Switching
Costs, Provided The Actual Costs Are Properly Identified.
The RTC agrees with the Commission that "[a] significant portion of local switching costs, however, likely do not vary with usage."(22) Therefore, "it is more reasonable and economically efficient to recover dedicated line card costs through flat charges."(23) The Commission's emphasis on cost causation principles(24) is also important.
Ameritech reports that "more than 40 percent of switching costs are NTS."(25) Over the life of a switch, software upgrades can account for the vast portion of the cost of the switch. Most of NTS software upgrades are necessitated by the demands of the interexchange network. For example, most local rural exchanges could be served by a private branch exchange (PBX). It is the toll network that demands an advanced digital switch. Also, mandates such as number portability increase the NTS costs of a switch.
Rural switching costs are higher per minute or per line than urban switching costs. This is due to small carriers' lack of economies of scope and scale, as well as the lower density of rural areas. The rationale for dial equipment minutes (DEM) weighting is based on this fact. Usage-sensitive costs, such as costs allocated by DEM weighting, still need to be recovered. While DEM weighting is a small cost recovery figure in the scheme of access charges, it represents a substantial amount of necessary support for small, rural LECs with demonstrably higher switching costs. Accordingly, the RTC agrees with the Commission's statement that there are usage-based costs that need to be recovered. Minutes of use charges will still be applicable in any new access charge regime and can be recovered with an explicit, flat rate, bulk billed mechanism. The RTC urges the Commission to consider the inherently higher switching costs (per unit) in rural areas when it examines both traffic sensitive and NTS costs in its rate-of-return proceeding.
C. Transport Costs Should Be Properly Identified And Shifted To The Correct
Elements.
The Commission seeks "comment on phasing out the TIC."(26) The RTC urges the Commission to carefully examine the nature of the costs that are contained within the transport interconnection charge (TIC). There is no basis in law or logic for the conclusion that the TIC can be phased out without considering the actual costs of transport. These costs of transport are especially important in remote, rural areas where the cost can be substantially higher. They are real costs, even if they may not all be allocated to the optimal access arrangement. The TIC is a legitimate revenue stream necessary for the provision of access and universal service by small, rural telephone companies. The Commission must fully examine and allocate the 80 percent of transport costs that are contained within the TIC and the 20 percent contained in other rate elements rather than simply phasing out all or part of the TIC.
Fortunately, the Commission is not planning to eliminate the TIC without inspecting the costs. In keeping with cost causation principles, the FCC proposes to "reassign costs included in the TIC to those rate elements to which they are related, including the different transport rate elements."(27) The RTC believes that, for NECA pool members, most of these costs can be isolated and identified. Obviously, due to inherent design differences between urban and rural networks, NECA pool member companies will have different transport costs than price cap companies.
Also, the RTC believes the Commission should examine the original methodology that was used to calculate the initial tandem-switched transport rates. The RTC is in general agreement "that the number of actual minutes traversing tandem circuits is significantly below 9000 minutes per month."(28) Transmission minutes are substantially lower in rural areas. In any
case, the Commission needs to use figures that are representative of NECA pool members when it revises its rules and applies them to rate-of-return companies.
The Commission states that its "goal in this proceeding is to establish a mechanism to phase out the TIC in a manner that fosters competition and responds to the court's remand."(29) The RTC suggests that cost causative principles will enable the Commission to respond to the court. As for a mechanism, transport costs should be included in access since they are a true cost of interconnection to the local network. These costs can be made explicit and bulk billed to the IXCs. The Commission should avoid transferring these costs to any new universal service fund or the end user. As long as the costs are properly identified, they should remain as part of transport rate charges or should be properly shifted to other areas. For example, analog switches require multiplexers to convert the traffic delivered over DS1 trunks to the DS0 level. These costs can be recovered in the local switching charge.
While the Commission is identifying each transport rate element, it must continue to bear in mind the high cost nature of rural areas. As SBC contends, "a study of its interoffice facilities indicates that transport may cost over five times more in low density areas than in high density areas."(30) Since many of these costs are contained in the TIC, the Commission must exercise caution if it phases out any part of the TIC since any adverse revenue impact from doing so will be exacerbated in rural areas. The Commission wisely recognizes this when it states, "some of the costs in the TIC may result from facility-based rates not reflecting the full costs of serving rural low density areas."(31) In addressing this rural disparity issue, the Commission seeks "comment on what modifications to our access charge rules for rate-of-return LECs are necessary to address any revisions to the TIC that may be adopted."(32) The RTC suggests that rural LECs be allowed to recover these legitimate costs of providing transport. Phasing out the TIC will not make the costs go away. With rational shifting of costs to their proper elements, while `keeping rural dynamics in mind, the Commission can devise a reasonable access mechanism for transport provided by rate-of-return LECs.
III. TRANSITION ISSUES
A. Universal Service
The NPRM proposes to revise Part 69 to reduce interstate costs to reflect any interstate revenues received from the new Universal Service mechanism and requests comment on possible revisions.(33) The present USF, DEM and LTS mechanisms work through the Part 36 separations rules. If the new universal support mechanisms are non-separations based, then Part 36 must be adjusted accordingly. The combination of the new mechanisms and the Part 36 rules must then be tested to ensure that the combined results meet the sufficient and predictable standards of section 254. Unfortunately, the Joint Board's recommendation does not specify what Part 36 rule changes would be incorporated in adoption of its proposal, and the NPRM notes that the Commission "must determine the extent to which universal support revenues are apportioned to the interstate jurisdiction."(34) The present Part 36 rules provide for an additional expense adjustment for common line cost, and an interstate allocation based on weighted DEM for traffic sensitive costs. Long Term Support (LTS) is interstate revenue which recovers interstate common line cost. If the Commission adopts the proposal to include DEM weighting and LTS in the new universal service mechanism, their character as interstate revenue should not change and the interstate revenue requirement will not change. In contrast, the new USF amounts for recovery of costs must follow the separations treatment ultimately assigned. Support from an interstate expense adjustment of federal universal service mechanism to moderate local and intrastate rates, however, cannot be deducted from interstate costs without becoming unavailable for use in the intrastate jurisdiction for the purpose for which they were intended.
B. Embedded costs
The NPRM recognizes that there is a legitimate argument that incumbent LECs need to recover any difference between their embedded costs and forward looking costs, and asks about the amount of such difference and the reason for the difference, whether the prudency of these historical costs should be determined now and what recovery mechanism should be used.(35) In the absence of forward looking cost studies, either by company or through proxies that have been validated for rural telephone companies, neither the RTC nor the Commission can quantify such differences at this time, or state particular reasons beyond those identified in the NPRM. The claims of various IXCs with a vested interest in reduced access charges that inefficiency and overinvestment are a major cause of the difference are simply unfounded. The difference between Hatfield or any other model estimates of investment and actual investment has not been demonstrated by anybody to represent a valid determination of the forward looking cost of any LEC or group of LECs.(36)
Each year since 1983, the IXCs have had the opportunity to challenge the individual or NECA tariff filings of the rural LECs and demonstrate that there is imprudent investment in their rate base. They have not done so, and should not be imagined to make a credible claim simply by repetition, without providing adjudicatory evidence.
If access rates were moved to a forward looking cost basis, the difference between the new definition of cost and the old definition would be a valid revenue requirement to be recovered, including the prescribed rate of return, over a reasonable period of time.
C. The Commission Must Adopt A Mechanism To Permit Small LEC Recovery
Of Costs Incurred In Response To A Federal And State Commission-Supervised Regulatory Scheme.
As stated above, the access approach adopted for LECs subject to price cap regulation
will necessarily affect the incumbent LECs that are not subject to price caps. The Commission
cannot adopt access rules in isolation in this proceeding and wait to separately correct whatever
adverse effects these rules will have on small LECs. Even if those rules are not specifically
addressed to small LECs, it is likely they will have an indirect or delayed reaction effect on them.
The issue of stranded investment is one of the issues that will have a greater adverse effect on
small LECs if the Commission proceeds from an erroneous legal or policy position. The
Commission should therefore consider how the stranded investment rules it adopts will affect
small LECs.
Small LECs are dependent on access charges and universal service fund revenues for
approximately 65% of their revenues. (37) This fact is not a coincidence but the result of federal and
state policies that were adopted to enable the delivery of ubiquitous telecommunications service
throughout the nation. The principal forces that have shaped industry structure and determined
how small LECs recover their interstate costs have been Commission policies and rules and the
federal mandates in the Rural Electrification Act as amended to include rural telephone borrowers.
Beginning with the adoption of the Joint Board recommendation to establish universal service
mechanisms, the Commission has recognized that the high costs of operating in rural areas
required rules to ensure that rural telephone companies could expand service and maintain
adequate service to existing customers. In Market Structure (Phase I), the Commission noted, "In
the context of this proceeding a 'universal service objective' means avoiding actions that would
cause a significant number of local exchange service subscribers to cancel that service."(38) The
former Rural Electrification Administration ("REA"now the Rural Utility Service ) also promoted
investment in rural areas in furtherance of federal goals and a statutory mandate that required
rural telephone borrowers to extend service to rural areas. Specifically, 7 U.S.C.§ 922 provides
that the RUS must "obtain assurance that the telephone service to be furnished or improved [ with
RUS loans] will be made available to the widest practical number of rural users." The RUS
regulations, 7 C.F.R.§ 1735.11, implement this statutory mandate by requiring RUS borrowers to
extend telephone service to "all interested potential subscribers in the service area" unless the
costs
would be exorbitant in particular situations.
The jurisdictional allocations that set the parameters for recovering large portions of nontraffic sensitive and traffic sensitive costs from interstate access charges are dictated by separations rules in Part 36 as well as the access charge rules in Part 69. These rules in turn reflect a goal to preserve a nationwide system "with adequate facilities at reasonable charges."(39) Congress has not abandoned but strengthened that goal by specifying that "quality services should be available at just, reasonable, and affordable rates," directing that support for universal service be "specific, predictable and sufficient(40) and adopting a policy committed to rural and urban availability of advanced telecommunications and information services."(41) Additionally, Congress has given the Commission new authority to order a LEC to provide interstate service to unserved communities.(42)
Of course, the 1996 Act indicates that Congress intended to promote competition and deregulation through the changes and new laws it adopted. However, there is no indication in the Act that Congress intended Commission rules to ignore past history or the effects of the prior regulatory regime as it enacts rules providing for a transition to the new regime. Indeed, it must be assumed that Congress intended that the Commission would enforce the 1996 Act in a manner that is consistent with fairness, that will be the least disruptive to consumers and the industry and that will comport with the just compensation requirements of the United States Constitution. The Commission thus correctly recognizes that it must consider a mechanism to compensate LECs for the stranded investment costs associated with the multiple changes resulting from access charge reform.(43) The mechanism that is developed should also provide for recovery of the stranded investment costs associated with the interconnection requirements, separations reform and removal of implicit universal service support. The result from the use of forward looking economic costs is no different, whether applied to access charges or pricing for interconnection and unbundled elements. In either case, incumbent LECs do not recover the embedded costs of facilities deployed under the old regulatory regime. Likewise, to the extent that separations changes shift costs to the intrastate jurisdiction, there must be some mechanism that permits LECs to recover from cost causers embedded costs incurred for interstate service.
A mechanism for recovery is appropriate because Commission policies and rules made pursuant to federal laws have specified the nature and extent of a LEC's duty to provide interstate access. Under Section 214 of the Communications Act, fully subject LECs providing access have been obligated to provide service until the Commission authorized discontinuance. Commission regulations required detailed showing of public need by LECs seeking to extend service by constructing or acquiring facilities.(44) Also, following the adoption of access charges, Commission dictates required LECs to make the investments required to provide equal access, 800 number portability, calling number delivery, and number portability. (45)
A basic tenet of utility rate making is that the costs associated with providing the facilities to enable these services should be borne by the cost causers. Adherence to this tenet requires a mechanism to prevent the loading of embedded costs onto the captive customers of LECs, whether these customers are purchasers of access or local ratepayers. The Commission has taken the right first step in recognizing that mandated forward looking cost methodologies may result in defining costs below embedded costs by billions of dollars. It must take the next step and recognize that prohibiting recovery of these costs by LECs will result in confiscation. The LECs that invested in plant to fulfill their common carrier obligations and comply with Commission requirements did so under rules that guaranteed they could set their rates to recover prudent investments. Fairness now requires that the Commission adopt measures to compensate the LECs for investments made in reliance on rules that permitted recovery of prudent investments, if it adopts a costing model that is forward looking and necessarily denies recovery of historical costs.
Recently, Chairman Hundt stated that the Commission must address the issue of incumbents' historic costs in its access and universal service proceedings.(46) The Chairman agreed that a valid argument exists for the recovery of historic or embedded costs and outlined questions that will need to be answered. The RTC urges the Commission to address in this proceeding in reference to all incumbents, including small LECS, these questions listed by the Chairman: How can historic or embedded costs be determined? When will the determination be proper? What revenues are to be counted to cover such costs? Who has jurisdiction over this issue? Who should pay the costs?
In answering each of these questions, the Commission should consider the approach used
by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission in connection with its order providing for the
unbundling of wholesale electric power.(47) The FERC concluded that wholesale costs might be
stranded as a result of its decision providing for open access transmission. It said it had the
responsibility to allow for the recovery of stranded costs because the prospect of not recovering
such costs could erode utilities' ability to attract capital and be very detrimental to a diverse array
of utility shareholders.(48) It also based its decision on a recognition that utilities had operated
under a regime that required them to invest in wholesale generation facilities and to make services
available on demand. It noted that it had been chided by the court for its inaction and failure to
address market distortions resulting from uneconomic producer-pipeline contracts over which it
had jurisdiction at a time when it was promulgating orders restructuring the natural gas
industry.(49)
The resulting disruption in telecommunications markets from the interconnection rules and
access charge reform will be similar to the expected disruption from the FERC's open access
order. The principles that the FERC has relied on apply to the analysis the Commission must
make and the questions it must answer with respect to the incumbent LECs that have operated
as regulated utilities, complied with and relied on Commission access charge rules, Commission
licensing and reporting requirements and Commission orders requiring the deployment of specific
technologies or infrastructure. The Commission will need to assess carefully the impact of its
trilogy of proceedings changing the regulatory regime. It should consider to what extent and how
its decisions will contribute to market collapse for certain incumbents that have heretofore had the
obligation to continue to provide service. The precise determination of jurisdictional issues and
the quantification of stranded costs will be difficult, but the Commission must nonetheless grapple
with these issues and act to ensure that its decision is lawful and reasonable. For example, the
Commission cannot ignore incumbent LEC obligations as carriers of last resort even though state
law has been the basis of these obligations. Incumbents have largely fulfilled the Commission's
universal service objective in the course of complying with state certification or franchising
requirements.
IV. "REFORMED" ACCESS CHARGE RULES SHOULD AVOID UNJUSTIFIED
DISCRIMINATION AND PREFERENCES, BENEFIT END USERS AND
COMPLY WITH THE NEW LAW'S UNIVERSAL SERVICE PROVISIONS.
A. Terminating Access Treatment Should Be The Same For Incumbents And
Their Competitors And Consistent With Fostering Efficient Use Of
Telecommunications Services.
The NPRM(50) asks about whether and in what way the Commission should regulate terminating access services. It raises this question for both price cap incumbent LECs and CLECs and seeks comment on whether the effects of competition will be the same for terminating and originating access. The NPRM also asks(51) whether all LECs should be permitted to collect terminating access from end users, whether the calling or called party should pay for terminating access and whether giving carriers facing a specified level of competition the flexibility to follow market signals in apportioning access charges between carrier customers and end users would be lawful under the section 254(g) requirement for averaging urban and high cost rural interexchange rates.
1. There Is No Justification For Discriminating Between ILECS And LECS In
Regulating Terminating Access.
The Commission itself identifies differences(52) between originating and terminating access, such as whether the calling party (originating access) or the receiving party (terminating access) decides to initiate the call, who chooses the service provider and who must pay for the call. It suggests that there is greater market power with regard to terminating access, since the called party chooses the access provider at the terminating end of the call, but the calling party initiates and pays for the call. Since the caller and his chosen interexchange carrier are unable to choose the terminating access provider, the Commission reasons (ibid.), this end of a call may retain bottleneck characteristics for whatever LEC serves the receiving party.(53) Significantly, whatever the level of terminating access market power, the Commission correctly acknowledges(54) that CLECs have the same potential for market power over terminating access as ILECs, because they are also not chosen by the calling party.
The NPRM contemplates different regulatory alternatives for ILECs and CLECs. However, the RTC believes that the similar situations in which ILECs and CLECs stand as to terminating access dictates that, above all, they must be subject to the same level of regulation or deregulation. Disparate regulation would competitively disadvantage the more restricted carrier
-- virtually certain (although unfairly) to be the ILEC. The Commission must have a better reason than its "extreme[ ] reluctan[ce]" to regulate competitive entrants(55) to justify treating similarly-circumstanced parties differently.(56) Moreover, if the Commission imposes regulation out of concern that the CLEC could overcharge for terminating access, it would be silly to measure the CLEC's charges against the ILEC's charges. Such a baseless comparison could amount to an invitation to overcharge for termination whenever the CLEC's costs were lower than the ILEC's. Even to require a CLEC to support its costs only when they exceed the ILEC's costs(57) would discriminate against the ILEC. In short, in regulating competitors where there is no significant difference to justify disparate requirements, the Commission should focus on even-handed, competitively neutral treatment, not on finding "less intrusive methods of ensuring a competitive LEC's terminating access charges are just and reasonable."
2. The Commission Should Not Discourage Efficient Use Of The Network By Charging The Called Party For Terminating Access.
The alternatives proposed in the NPRM are inadequate:
First, imposing a rate ceiling based on "forward-looking economic costs" by requiring only an ILEC to produce a TSLRIC study(58) or by comparing the ILEC's interconnection prices under sections 251 and 252 with its terminating access charges (ibid.) would both discriminate against the ILEC and conflict with the Act's deregulatory and procompetitive purposes and the marketplace negotiation model that is the fundamental policy of the interconnection provisions. The Commission should discard those alternatives.
Second, recovering all ILEC originating and terminating access costs in the originating
access charges or a flat charge would at least impose the cost of terminating access on the party
deciding to make the call. However, disproportionately high originating access charges in high
cost areas would increase the pressure on interexchange carriers to deaverage rural and urban toll
rates, undermining geographically averaged toll rates, discourage interexchange carriers from
competing in high cost areas and impose disproportionate support requirements on the interstate
carrier of last resort, contrary to section 254(d). However, these universal service problems
could at least be remedied with suitable universal service support arrangements.(59)
Third, and perhaps most damaging to the efficient network use pursued by the legislation and Commission policies, would be a requirement(60) to recover terminating access charges from the called party, as wireless carriers have done in the past. The Commission rightly calls attention to the concern that charging a party for receiving calls would result in unanswered calls. It is familiar information that many cellular telephone subscribers do not make their wireless telephone numbers known widely to avoid having to pay for receiving unwanted telephone calls.(61) The same result would be likely, but on a larger scale, if answering the wireline telephone exposed the passive recipient of the call to terminating access charges. Creating incentives not to accept telephone calls could, in turn, discourage full and efficient use of the public switched network that would maximize the value obtained for the resources involved in providing service.
Owing to the adverse effects of the heavily regulatory interventions it has proposed for terminating traffic, the Commission should seek a more flexible approach. Such an approach should not only apply the same terminating access charge requirements for ILECs and CLECs, but should also seriously consider allowing all such LECs to set their terminating access charges in response to market signals, subject to the requirement to justify their actual cost of such terminating service upon a complaint, supported by evidence of inconsistent charges for similar service or other information sufficient to warrant further Commission investigation.
B. The Commission Should Require Interexchange Carriers To Pass All Access Charge
Reductions Through To Their End Users.
The Commission focuses almost entirely on the need for pro-competitive and deregulatory reforms in the access charge system. While these are, indeed, central concerns under the 1996 Act, they share center stage with the Act's strong commitment to universal service and nationwide network development (sec. 254). Even in a competitive environment, section 254 teaches, regulators should ensure that all customers benefit from evolving telecommunications, including those for whom marketplace forces cannot yet be relied upon as the sole force behind "just, reasonable and affordable rates," "reasonably comparable" urban rural rates and services, access to advanced and telecommunications and information services and parity in interexchange rates for urban and rural customers and from state-to-state.
Interexchange carriers have worked ceaselessly and apparently successfully (e.g., ¶ 41) to persuade the Commission of the need to reduce their access charges; and ILECs have shown the importance of allowing them to set their charges far more flexibly in the competitive era ushered in by the 1996 Act. The NPRM suggests,(62) as an expected consumer benefit, that interexchange rates will decrease when access charges decrease. The Commission's faith that interexchange competition will provide interexchange customers with rates based on economic cost -- presumably forward-looking cost -- is dubious, given the immediate interstate rate increases by the three largest interexchange carriers when the Commission declared AT&T non-dominant and forbade tariffs for virtually all its services.(63) Indeed, the Commission has never performed a reality check on the competitive interstate market it claims credit for fostering. It should take advantage of the opportunity to test the outcome of its predictions for interstate competition by collecting sufficient information from the interexchange carriers -- who are forever touting TELRIC and TSLRIC for LECs -- to demonstrate whether their competitive interstate interexchange rates actually reflect forward-looking economic cost.
In the meantime, the Commission should prescribe a proportional pass through by all interexchange carriers of all access charge reductions to all classes of customers in the form of lower interexchange rates. The statute requires no less, since it calls for rate parity for rural and urban customers and for customers in different states and for "reasonably comparable" rural and urban rates and services. Allowing interexchange providers instead to use their access savings solely to benefit large, corporate and urban customers or to increase their profitability would sacrifice the interests of rural consumers and small businesses to deaveraging the Act seeks to mitigate.
C. The Commission Cannot Justify Forbearing From Enforcing The Act's Geographic
Interexchange Rate Averaging Requirement Rather Than Providing "Sufficient"
Universal Service Support To Make The Policy Work.
The Commission seeks comment(64) on whether it can lawfully require interexchange carriers to recover CCL costs by means of a flat-rated end user charge that differs from state to state or between rural and urban areas. If section 254 prevents such a charge, asks the NPRM, "do conditions exist sufficient to require the Commission to forbear from the application of section 254(g) to IXC recovery of flat rate charges from their end users?" Later in the NPRM,(65) the Commission asks about the effect of allowing geographically deaveraged charges for access elements, in light of the averaging requirements of section 254(g)(1)-(2). The short answer is that the Commission cannot justify taking any action or forbearing from enforcing any provision of law that will imperil geographic toll rate averaging or rural-urban rate and service comparability.
The RTC is not aware of any bar to requiring or allowing ILECs to bulk-bill assess flat-rate CCL access charges on interexchange carriers. However, that is not the case with regard to imposing flat rate end user charges that vary among the states or between rural and urban areas. The language of section 254(g) is unambiguous: "Providers of interexchange telecommunications services," it ordains, are not permitted to charge rates to their "subscribers" that are higher than rates they charge subscribers in " rural and high cost areas" or (b) that in any state exceed "the rates charged to its subscribers in any other state." The Act thus establishes interexchange rate parity as a standard for universal service and consumer protection against contrary marketplace pressures. In effect, it fleshes out the Act's requirements for "just," "reasonable," and "not unjustly or unreasonably discriminatory" rates and terms. Similarly, the universal service section involves criteria for what ends "protection of customers" should achieve. The forbearance standards in section 10 of the 1996 Act (See NPRM, n.54) basically ask whether laws and regulations can be repealed without sacrificing these purposes.
Consequently, to justify forbearing from section 254(g), the Commission must be able to conclude either (1) that the marketplace will provide interexchange rate parity and protect customers, as the universal service provision requires, without the specified regulatory intervention or, at the very least, (2) that it is no longer unjustly and unreasonably discriminatory or inadequately protective of customers in high cost areas or states to permit deaveraging of interexchange rates. Congress must necessarily have believed that the universal service provisions were necessary when it adopted the Act, or it would not have included the specific interexchange averaging, rural-urban comparability and other requirements in section 254.
For interexchange carriers to impose flat rates that differ from rural to urban and state to state is unmistakably at odds with the unqualified prohibition against "higher" charges for customers in high cost areas or high cost states.(66) Nor is there any indication that circumstances have changed so radically since adoption of the Act that the marketplace alone will maintain the rate parity Congress mandated. Finally, there is no reason to claim, much less to assume, that deaveraged charges will be any less unjust and discriminatory or will protect consumers a bit more adequately now than when the Act was enacted. It is particularly peculiar for the Commission (a) to report the Joint Board's recommendation against raising the SLC (¶ 64) but (b) to consider establishing a second deaveraged and apparently uncapped flat rate charge per customer for interexchange access (¶ 60) that is indistinguishable from an uncapped and deaveraged SLC and (c) to assume that this deaveraged neo-SLC protects consumers well enough and is sufficiently in the public interest to require Section 10 forbearance. That conclusion cannot be rationally entertained. The Commission should, thus, reject out of hand any proposal to forbear from applying section 254(g) as written.
The Commission's reasonable concern(67) about the impact on interexchange carriers from allowing geographically deaveraged charges warrants further action under section 254. Such action is necessary to maintain averaging of interexchange end user rates without (a) forcing an illegal "implicit" subsidy on interexchange carriers, (b) discouraging interexchange competition in high cost rural areas and states or (c) and exacting an unequal contribution to support universal service from some interexchange service providers. The pressure to deaverage interexchange rates increases when access charges imposed on interexchange carriers serving only selective markets or regions are deaveraged to levels that further augment the differential in rates for serving high cost areas and rural states. AT&T, for example, has sought to deaverage rates regionally to better its competitive position. Coupled with the Commission's recent decision to detariff all interstate charges, with minimal provision for enforcing statutory rate averaging,(68) the incentive for deaveraging or diminishing service to high cost places is likely to become ever more compelling. And the clear, although indirect, consequence is to impose implicit subsidy obligations on interexchange carriers that serve high cost routes and to exact discriminatory universal service contributions from these carriers because they cannot lawfully eliminate or degrade the quality of interexchange service on high cost routes. These implicit subsidy and disproportionate universal service contribution burdens are likely to fall most heavily upon AT&T, with its nationwide carrier of last resort obligations, and the large LECs that have similar obligations for intrastate toll service. Conversely, interexchange carriers that shun high cost service receive a double competitive boost from escaping the support and contribution obligations and from further ability to cream skim at still lower rates.
There are two ways to remedy these conflicts with section 254 and remove impediments to true competition:
First, the Commission must reconvene the Joint Board charged with implementing section 254. That Joint Board proceeding could then adopt "specific, predictable and sufficient" mechanisms to compensate interexchange carriers that are duly designated as eligible for universal service support pursuant to section 214(e)(2) or (3). The mechanism would allow these interexchange carriers to recover from the high cost fund for the higher costs incurred in providing lawfully averaged interexchange service to fulfill their universal service obligations on routes where deaveraged access charges result in higher than average costs.
The second alternative would be for the reconvened Joint Board to adopt "specific,
predictable and sufficient" mechanisms to reduce the access charge disparity for routes on which
the marketplace alone would not otherwise provide service at lawful averaged rates. The second
alternative is preferable for at least three reasons: First, the result of supporting access charges
would be to encourage interexchange carriers to serve, continue to serve and not to
surreptitiously deaverage the rates on high cost routes. Second, it would be easier to enforce the
requirement in section 254(e) that support must be used for the "facilities and services for which
the support is intended" when the support is targeted to precisely the access costs which raise
interexchange carriers' cost for rural routes. And, third, support would be directed to the carriers that are already eligible by state designation, maintaining administrative simplicity.
V. THE COMMISSION MUST PERFORM A REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY
ANALYSIS AND CONSIDER HOW ITS DECISION WILL AFFECT THE
ECONOMIC INTERESTS OF SMALL INCUMBENT LECS.
In its Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA), the Commission incorrectly concludes that its rules will not have a significant economic impact on "small entities" otherwise protected by the Regulatory Flexibility Act ("RFA").(69) There is no factual basis for the Commission's cursory conclusion that the rules would only apply to carriers subject to price cap regulation. As the RTC has shown above, whatever access charge rules are adopted in this proceeding will affect approximately 65% of the revenues of its small LEC member companies. As shown below, these LECs are "small entities" despite the Commission's repeated assertions to the contrary. The Commission is required to consider adverse economic impacts its rules may have on these companies whenever it promulgates a rule that requires public comment under the Administrative Procedure Act.(70)
In this and other proceedings implementing the Act, the Commission has attempted to evade its obligation under the RFA by relying on an erroneous definition of "small entities." According to the Commission, incumbent LECs are not "small entities" because they are "dominant" in their field. In 1986, the Commission first concluded that the Regulatory Flexibility Act did not apply to incumbent LECs, no matter how small. At that time, it reasoned that every incumbent LEC, no matter how small was not a "small entity" under Section 3 of the Small Business Act based on its interpretation of that act.(71) In a Report and Order released in 1987, the Commission simply affirmed its 1986 conclusion with the cursory statement, "[n]o argument has been advanced that would cause us to modify that determination."(72)
The Commission notes in this NPRM that the RFA defines a "small business" to be the same as a "small business concern" under the Small Business Act.(73) To be precise, the RFA provides:
the term 'small business' has the same meaning as the term 'small business concern'
under section 3 of the Small Business Act, unless an agency, after consultation with the
Office of Advocacy of the small Business Administration and after opportunity for public
comment, establishes one or more definitions of such term which are appropriate to the
activities of the agency and publishes such definition(s) in the Federal Register.
Section 3 of the Small Business Act in turn, among other things, states that "a small -business-concern . . . shall be deemed to be one which is independently owned and operated and which is not dominant in its field of operation. . . ." 15 U.S.C. § 632(a)(1). The SBA Administrator may use additional criteria in defining a small-business-concern but other federal agencies are prohibitied from so doing without first pertaining SBA approval and providing for public notie and comment. 15 U.S.C. § 632(a)(2). SBA regulations implement Section 3 of the Small Business Act by providing that other agencies must use SBA regulations that define whether a business entity is small unless they establish a different definition that complies with SBA requirements and that receives the approval of the SBA Administrator.(74) The Commission skirts these requirement, by referring to 15 U.S.C. § 632 (a)(1) alone, defying 15 U.S.C. § 632 (a)(2) and SBA regulations which prohibits it from prescribing the definition of a "small entity" and relying on its 1987 prior conclusion that incumbent LECs are dominant.
The Commission's failure to abide by all the provisions of the RFA is improper. Section 3 of the SBA gives the SBA clear authority to look at size criteria in determining dominance for purposes of its definition of a "small entity." 15 U.S.C. § 632 (a)(2)(B)states that the SBA may utilize number of employees, dollar volume of business, net worth, net income, a combination thereof or other appropriate criteria in determining factors under 632 (a)(1) which includes dominance. This is what the SBA has done in promulgating 13 C.F.R., Part 121 which defines what businesses are "small entities" in terms of size. Those size standards already take into account "economic characteristics comprising the structure of an industry, including degree of competition, average firm size, start-up costs and entry barriers, and distribution of firms by size."(75) The regulations specifically state that "[s]ize standards seek to ensure that a concern that meets a specific size standard is not dominant in its field of operation."(76)
The Commission acknowledges that SBA rules define a small telecommunications entity as one with 1,500 employees but insists that all incumbent LECs are dominant and factors that conclusion into its determination of whether any incumbent is a "small entity." Of course, this is wrong. The SBA is charged with defining what a "small entity" is and that agency has already considered the statutory criteria of "dominance" in arriving at its definition. If every agency required to comply with the RFA were allowed to flout federal statutes and SBA regulations as the Commission has done here, the rights granted small businesses under the RFA would soon become mneaningless. That, of course, is not what Congress intends as it most recently demonstrated by strengthening the RFA to provide for judicial review.(77)
Small incumbent LECs meeting the SBA's definition of "small entity" are among the class of carriers that will be affected by the access charge changes proposed in this NPRM. It is therefore imperative that the Commission perform an RFA analysis so that it may consider any adverse impact the proposed rules will have on these companies and review alternatives which may reduce adverse impacts on the companies.
CONCLUSION
The RTC urges the Commission to promulgate rules that are consistent with the above comments and that take account of the interests of the small incumbent LECs providing service to high cost areas.
Respectfully submitted,
THE RURAL TELEPHONE COALITION
NRTA NTCA OPASTCO
By: By: By:
Margot Smiley Humphrey David Cosson Lisa M. Zaina
By: By:
L. Marie Guillory Kenneth Johnson
Koteen & Naftalin, LLP 2626 Pennsylvania Ave, NW 21 Dupont Circle, NW
1150 Connecticut Ave, NW Washington, DC 20037 Suite 700
Suite 1000 (202) 298-2300 Washington, DC 20036
Washington, DC 20036 (202) 659-5990
(202) 467-5700
January 29, 1997
1. NPRM, ¶ 13.
2. NPRM, ¶ 41.
3. See, e.g., Reply Comments of the National Telephone Cooperative Association to the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in CC Docket No. 80-286, at 22, 45 (Nov. 9, 1995); Comments of NTCA to the Notice of Inquiry in CC Docket No. 80-286, at 33-35, 66 (Oct. 28, 1994); see also, Reply Comments of NTCA to NYNEX Petition for Waiver of Parts 61 and 69 for a Transition Plan to Preserve Universal Service in a Competitive Environment in DA 93-1573, at 4 n.3 (Mar. 2, 1994).
4. If the Commission prevails before the 8th Circuit, its rules regarding the burden of proof and standards for state decisions on retention of exemption from Section 251(c) will remain in place. These rules are based on the philosophy that exemption is not favored and cannot be maintained where the only harm is that caused by "efficient competitive entry." In Re Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, First Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-98, FCC 96-325, ¶¶ 831-2 (Aug. 8, 1996). Under these rules, which the Commission supports, many rural telephone companies can be expected to have unbundled elements requirements. The Commission cannot logically argue both that the exemption should only rarely be continued and that access reform is not now needed by rural telephone companies because they will be exempt.
5. NPRM, ¶ 42.
6. NPRM, ¶ 43.
7. See NPRM, ¶ 55.
8. NPRM, ¶ 21.
9. See, In re MTS and WATS Market Structure, Third Report and Order, 97 F.C.C.2d 682 (1983), second recon., 97 F.C.C.2d 834 (1984).
10. NPRM, ¶ 59.
11. NPRM, ¶ 59.
12. NPRM, ¶ 60.
13. NPRM, ¶ 61.
14. NPRM, ¶ 60.
15. NPRM, ¶ 65.
16. Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No 96-45, Recommended Decision, FCC 96J-3 (rel. Nov. 8, 1996) (Joint Board Recommended Decision), ¶¶ 90-91.
17. 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(2).
18. NPRM, ¶ 65.
19. 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(2).
20. 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(3).
21. Id.
22. NPRM, ¶ 72.
23. Id.
24. NPRM, ¶ 73.
25. Id.
26. NPRM, ¶ 84.
27. NPRM, ¶ 92.
28. NPRM, ¶ 94.
29. NPRM, ¶ 98.
30. NPRM, ¶ 107.
31. NPRM, ¶ 121.
32. NPRM, ¶ 122.
33. NPRM, ¶ 246.
34. NPRM, ¶ 245. The Commission must make clear the separations treatment in its action on the Joint Board's recommendation.
35. NPRM, ¶¶ 247-270.
36. See, Reply Comments of U S West, Inc. to Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, CC Docket No. 96-45, at 11-14 (May 10, 1996); Comments of RTC to Public Notice, DA 96-1087, CC Docket No. 96-45, at 13 (Aug. 2, 1996); Comments of RTC and GVWN, Inc.-Management to Public Notice, DA 97-88, CC Docket No. 96-45, at 13-15, 16-21 (Jan. 24, 1977).
37. USDA, RUS, 1995 Statistical Report of Rural Telecommunications Borrowers, (1996).
38. 93 F.C.C.2d 241, 266 (1983).
39. 47 U.S.C. § 151.
40. 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(5) and (6).
41. 47 U.S.C.§ 254 (b)(2) and (5).
42. 47 U.S.C. § 214 (e) (3).
43. NPRM, ¶ 248.
44. 47 C.F.R. § 63.01-601. The Commission is proposing to forbear from imposing its Section 214 requirements on some carriers but the small LECs that are regulated under rate of return and that it still considers dominant will still be subject to filing requirements. Also, the commission is proposing a longer notification period for discontinuances or reductions in service that involve the small LECs. It proposes a 60 day period for the dominant LEC regulated under rate of return but concludes that a 30 day period should apply to price cap carriers.
45. In re MTS and WATS Market Structure and Amendment of Part 69 of the Commission's Rules for Recovery of Equal Access Costs, CC Docket No. 78-72, Report and Order, 4 FCC Rcd 2104 (1989). In re Telephone Number Portability, Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 11 FCC Rcd 8352 (1996). In re Provision of Access for 800 Service, Report and Order, 4 FCC Rcd 2824 (1989) . In re Rules and Policies Regarding Calling Number Identification, Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 9 FCC Rcd 1764 (1994).
46. Speech to Competitive Policy Institute on January 14, 1997.
47. Order 888 etc. (SEE MARIE)
48. Id., at 84.
49. Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Services by Public Utilities Recovery of Stranded Costs, 75 F.E.R.C. 1080, n.586 (1996), referring to American Gas Distributors v. FERC, 824 F.2d 981, 1021 (D.C.Cir. 1987).
50. 50 NPRM, ¶ 272.
51. 51 NPRM, ¶ 215.
52. 52 NPRM, ¶ 271.
53. 53The NPRM further observes in n.357 that, under section 254(g), "the cost of high terminating access rates is spread among all end users."
54. 54 NPRM, ¶ 279.
55. 55 NPRM, ¶ 278.
56. 56 See, Melody Music v. FCC, 345 F.2d 730 (D.C. Cir. 1965).
57. 57 NPRM, ¶ 280.
58. 58 NPRM, ¶ 274.
59. 59 See Section IV. 5, infra.
60. 60 NPRM, ¶ 275.
61. 61The cellular industry may be moving away from charging for incoming calls. In any event, the cellular user knows he or she will be charged the per minute rate when a call is answered. Wireline users, on the other hand, without caller ID, would not know when the charge applies until it is too late to avoid it.
62. 62 See, ¶ 42.
63. 63 See, Communications Daily, "AT&T Raises Rates 5.9% on Residential Long Distance, MCI 4.9%," pp 1-2 (Friday, Nov. 29, 1996).
64. 64 NPRM, ¶ 63.
65. 65 NPRM, ¶ 186.
66. 66A nationwide average charge per interexchange end user would not present either the need for forbearance or the conflict with rural parity of the approach suggested in the NPRM.
67. 67 NPRM, ¶¶ 186.
68. 68 The RTC has filed a request for reconsideration of the Commission's detariffing decision.
69. 69 NPRM, para 346.
70. 70 5 U.S.C. §§ 603, 604.
71. 71 Regulation of Small Telephone Companies, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 51 Fed. Reg. 45912 (proposed December 23, 1986).
72. 72 Regulation of Small Telephone Companies, Report and Order, 2 FCC Rcd 3811, 3815 (1987).
73. 73 NPRM, para 347.
74. 74 13 C.F.R. § 121.902.
75. 75 Id.
76. 76 Id.
77. 77 Section 242 of Small Business Growth and Fairness Act of 1996, Pub. L. 104-121. These protections now give a small entity adversely affected by final agency action the right to judicial review of agency compliance with the requirements of Sections 601, 604, 605(b) and 610 of the RFA.