Before the
FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
Washington, D.C. 20554
In the Matter of )
)
Access Charge Reform ) CC Docket No. 96-262
)
Price-Cap Performance Review ) CC Docket No. 94-1
for Local Exchange Carriers )
)
Transport Rate Structure ) CC Docket No. 91-213
and Pricing )
)
Use of the Public Switched ) CC Docket No. 96-263
Network by Information Service )
and Internet Access Providers )
COMMENTS OF
FRONTIER CORPORATION
Table of Contents
Page
Summary ...................................................................................................... ii
Introduction .................................................................................................. 1
Argument ...................................................................................................... 4
I. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ELIMINATE THE
CARRIER COMMON LINE CHARGE ............................................... 4
II. THE COMMISSION SHOULD PHASE-OUT THE
TRANSPORT INTERCONNECTION CHARGE ................................ 8
III. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ADOPT A COMBINED
PRESCRIPTIVE/MARKET-BASED APPROACH TO
ACCESS CHARGE REFORM ........................................................... 10
A. The Commission Should Adopt a
Prescriptive Approach To Adjust Access
Rate Levels ............................................................................ 11
B. The Commission Should Adopt a Market-
Based Approach to Pricing Flexibility ....................................
14
IV. THE COMMISSION SHOULD DECLINE TO TINKER
WITH THE EXISTING LOCAL SWITCHING AND
TRUNKING RATE ELEMENTS ........................................................ 17
V. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ELIMINATE THE
ENHANCED SERVICES PROVIDER EXEMPTION
FROM THE ASSESSMENT OF INTERSTATE
ACCESS CHARGES ....................................................................... 19
Conclusion ................................................................................................. 21
Summary
Frontier(1) on behalf of its incumbent local exchange, competitive local
exchange and interexchange operations, submits these comments on the
Commission's Notice initiating this proceeding. In the Notice portion of these
consolidated proceedings, the Commission seeks comment on a number of
proposals to reform fundamentally the existing interstate access charge regime.
The Commission has correctly described this proceeding as a part of the trilogy of
the most important proceedings (together with its Interconnection and Universal
Service proceedings) emanating from the Telecommunications Act of 1996.
Frontier agrees that not only is access reform painfully needed in and of itself, but
also that the Commission needs to reconcile the decisions it reaches here with
those that are ultimately reached in the Interconnection and Universal Service
proceedings.
The Commission's beginning assumption -- that the current level of access
charges is simply too high -- is generally correct. Access charges -- like the rates
ultimately developed for unbundled elements -- need to be aligned with the
economic costs of providing service. However, the Commission should revise a
number of the assumptions and tentative conclusions that it reaches in the Notice.
First, the Commission should eliminate the interstate CCL charge. This
charge represents a substantial portion of access charges assessed by incumbent
local exchange carriers. In the case of Frontier's exchange carrier subsidiaries, for
example, 14.9% of their total interstate access revenues are derived from the CCL
charge. Yet, the CCL charge represents nothing more than an anachronistic cost
misallocation. The Commission should shift CCL cost recovery in the most
economically appropriate way to that identifiable class of customers that are the
cost-causers with respect to the local loop, namely end-user customers. The
Commission's alternative proposals represent no more than second-best
alternatives.
Second, the Commission should phase-down and eliminate TIC. The
Commission and, where necessary, a Joint Board, should identify and correct any
cost misallocations that result in the TIC of its current magnitude. However,
regardless of whatever cost misallocations are identified, the Commission should
act, over a fairly short period of time, to remove the TIC from interstate access
charges.
Third, the Commission should combine certain aspects of its proposed
market-based and prescriptive approaches to access charge reform. The two
approaches address different concerns -- the alignment of access rates with
economic costs, on the one hand, and the alignment of exchange carriers' ability
to compete in the face of changed market conditions, on the other. Both
approaches are complementary. Thus, the Commission should both mandate a
phase-down, over a relatively short period of time, of access rates and increase the
pricing flexibility it offers to exchange carriers in light of objective market evidence
that such flexibility is warranted.
Fourth, the Commission should decline to mandate an overly complex
access rate structure. Adoption of the proposals for further unbundling contained
in the Notice is likely not worth the effort or cost that it would impose on incumbent
local exchange carriers and interstate access customers alike.
Finally, the Commission should require enhanced services providers to pay
interstate access charges that reflect the costs that they cause. The ESP
exemption was adopted over twelve years ago as a transitional mechanism to
address concerns unique to an infant industry. The ESP industry has, by now,
grown up. There is no reason for the Commission to continue to afford this industry
special regulatory protection.
1. 1 Abbreviations used in this summary are defined in the text.
Introduction
Frontier Corporation ("Frontier"), on behalf of its incumbent local exchange,
competitive local exchange and interexchange operations, submits these comments
on the Commission's Notice initiating this proceeding.(1) In the Notice portion of
these consolidated proceedings, the Commission seeks comment on a number of
proposals to reform fundamentally the existing interstate access charge regime.
The Commission has correctly described this proceeding as a part of the trilogy of
the most important proceedings (together
with its Interconnection(2) and Universal Service(3) proceedings) emanating from the
Telecommunications Act of 1996 ("Act").(4) Frontier agrees that not only is access
reform painfully needed in and of itself, but also that the Commission needs to
reconcile the decisions it reaches here with those that are ultimately reached in the
Interconnection and Universal Service proceedings.
The Commission's beginning assumption -- that the current level of access
charges is simply too high(5) -- is generally correct. Access charges -- like the rates
ultimately developed for unbundled elements -- need to be aligned with the
economic costs of providing service. However, the Commission should revise a
number of the assumptions and tentative conclusions that it reaches in the Notice.
First, the Commission should eliminate the interstate carrier common line
charge ("CCL"). This charge represents a substantial portion of access charges
assessed by incumbent local exchange carriers. In the case of Frontier's exchange
carrier subsidiaries, for example, 14.9% of their total interstate access revenues are
derived from the CCL charge. Yet, the CCL charge represents nothing more than
an anachronistic cost misallocation. The Commission should shift CCL cost
recovery in the most economically appropriate way to that identifiable class of
customers that are the cost-causers with respect to the local loop, namely end-user
customers. The Commission's alternative proposals represent no more than
second-best alternatives.
Second, the Commission should phase-down and eliminate the transport
interconnection charge ("TIC"). The Commission and, where necessary, a Joint
Board, should identify and correct any cost misallocations that result in the TIC of
its current magnitude. However, regardless of whatever cost misallocations are
identified, the Commission should act, over a fairly short period of time, to remove
the TIC from interstate access charges.
Third, the Commission should combine certain aspects of its proposed
market-based and prescriptive approaches to access charge reform. The two
approaches address different concerns -- the alignment of access rates with
economic costs, on the one hand, and the alignment of exchange carriers' ability
to compete in the face of changed market conditions, on the other. Both
approaches are complementary. Thus, the Commission should both mandate a
phase-down, over a relatively short period of time, of access rates and increase the
pricing flexibility it offers to exchange carriers in light of objective market evidence
that such flexibility is warranted.
Fourth, the Commission should decline to mandate an overly complex
access rate structure. Adoption of the proposals for further unbundling contained
in the Notice is likely not worth the effort or cost that it would impose on incumbent
local exchange carriers and interstate access customers alike.
Finally, the Commission should require enhanced services providers
("ESPs") to pay interstate access charges that reflect the costs that they cause.
The ESP exemption was adopted over twelve years ago as a transitional
mechanism to address concerns unique to an infant industry. The ESP industry
has, by now, grown up. There is no reason for the Commission to continue to afford
this industry special regulatory protection.
Argument
I. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ELIMINATE THE
CARRIER COMMON LINE CHARGE. (Paragraphs
51-70)
The carrier common line ("CCL") charge represents nothing more than an
economically unsound subsidy from interexchange carriers to end-user subscribers.
The Commission is, therefore, correct in concluding that the CCL charge -- because
it recovers non-traffic sensitive ("NTS") costs on a usage-sensitive basis - is
economically inefficient.(6) However, the Commission's tentative conclusion -- and
the parallel conclusion of the Universal Service Joint Board(7) -- that some form of the
CCL charge should be retained is misplaced.
Fundamentally, the Commission's tentative conclusions -- and the alternative
recommendations that flow from those conclusions -- ignore the fact that
interexchange carriers do not cause the costs associated with the local loop. Those
costs are the same, regardless of whether an individual end-user subscriber makes
a large volume of -- or no -- interstate, interexchange calls. Exchange carriers
supply loops to provide telephone service to end-user subscribers. Therefore,
assigning any portion of the costs associated with the loop for recovery from
interexchange carriers is economically inefficient, regardless of the particular
method of recovery chosen.(8) Continuing the CCL charge would perpetuate a
subsidy that is both inconsistent with the Act and that the Commission should
eliminate in any event.
In addition, eliminating the CCL charge would not require the Commission
to shift the entirety of the current CCL revenue requirement into a universal service
fund.(9) Rather, the Commission should assign responsibility for recovery of all loop
costs allocated to the interstate jurisdiction -- at least for price cap carriers -- to end
users.(10) At the same time, it should raise the existing $3.50 per month cap on primary residential and single-line business customers to permit
this reallocation of cost recovery responsibility. End-user subscribers constitute the
best and a readily identifiable class of customers that are the cost-causers with
respect to loop costs. The Commission should, therefore, assign those costs to that
class of customers.
Moreover, the magnitude of the rise in the subscriber line charge ("SLC") to
accomplish this economically rational shift need not be dramatic. The current multi-line business SLC for Frontier's largest exchange carrier subsidiary -- Rochester
Telephone Corp. -- is currently $4.59. Thus, it would take an increase of only $1.09
per month in the residential and single-line business SLC to achieve parity across
all end-user customers and recover the entirety of the base factor portion from end-user charges. An increase of this magnitude is economically justifiable and could
not rationally be classified as draconian or a threat to universal service.(11)
The Commission's proposals to increase the current caps on the SLC for
additional residential lines and for multi-line business customers(12) are unworkable and insufficient to correct the existing anomaly. The administrative
tasks of determining what is a primary residential line or even what constitutes a
second line are daunting and invite efforts to game the system (e.g., subscribing to
a second line to a residence in another family member's name). In addition, shifting
the burden of CCL recovery onto multi-line business customers is both anti-competitive and economically inefficient. Forcing more common line recovery onto
multi-line business customers will do no more than encourage further uneconomic
bypass of the switched network. In particular, with alternative local competitors
entering the market that are not under a regulatory mandate to assess any SLC,
incumbent local exchange carriers should not be forced -- and may not have the
option, if the proposed regime were optional -- of increasing multi-line business
SLCs without sacrificing customers to competitors for reasons other than relative
economic efficiency.
Moreover, such a regime would be economically inefficient, as it would
merely shift the current subsidy to residential and single-line business subscribers
from interexchange carriers to large business customers. The Commission's
proposal fails to acknowledge, much less address, the subsidy that the CCL
represents.
Rather than continuing the attempt to sidestep this issue, the Commission
should confront it directly. The only economically rational solution is to eliminate
the carrier common line charge and shift responsibility for recovery of loop costs
allocated to the interstate jurisdiction to end-user subscribers.(13)
II. THE COMMISSION SHOULD PHASE-OUT THE
TRANSPORT INTERCONNECTION CHARGE.
(Paragraphs 96-122)
The transport interconnection charge ("TIC") represents the second largest
subsidy element contained in interstate access charges. In the case of Frontier's
exchange carrier subsidiaries, it recovers over half of the revenues allocated to the
trunking basket and 5.7% of their switched access revenues. When the
Commission restructured the transport rate elements to price transport elements
more in line with costs, this huge residual remained.(14) Although portions of these
residual costs constitute a subsidy, other portions may result from separations
anomalies or cost misallocations embedded in the Commission's accounting rules.(15)
Because of the existence of these anomalies, a flash-cut elimination of the TIC
would be unfair. Rather, in conjunction with the combined prescriptive/market-based approach to access charge reform that Frontier advocates below,(16) the
Commission should permit exchange carriers to identify and reallocate any
misallocated costs and recover those costs from the appropriate rate elements
and/or jurisdictions.(17) Coincident with the identification and correction of whatever
cost or jurisdictional misallocations may exist, the Commission should proceed with
expedition to eliminate the TIC.
III. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ADOPT A COMBINED
PRESCRIPTIVE/MARKET-BASED APPROACH TO
ACCESS CHARGE REFORM. (Paragraphs 140-240)
The Commission posits its market-based and prescriptive approaches to
access charge reform essentially as alternatives to producing cost-based access
charges.(18) The two approaches actually address different concerns: (1) the
prescriptive approach should address overall access rate levels; and (2) the
market-based approach should address pricing flexibility issues within the context
of an overall cap on interstate access rates.(19)
As a solution to the uneconomic pricing of switched access, the market-based approach assumes that substantial, near-term competition for switched
access services will exist. The most credible evidence suggests that the contrary,
in fact, will be the case. The Act certainly opens the door for such competition, but
it will not be a reality for years to come. Exchange access competitors must still
build out networks and must be able to obtain unbundled elements at economically
reasonable prices. The sheer number of cases that have had to go to arbitration --
not to mention the current and anticipated court challenges -- suggests that
significant local competition is some years away. As a result, it would be unwise
for the Commission to rely solely on market forces to reduce rates to economic
costs. Thus, for purposes of realigning rate levels, the Commission should rely
upon a prescriptive approach.
However, there should be little doubt that local competition is, in fact, on the
horizon. The Commission should not permit its price cap rules to be utilized to
preclude exchange carriers from operating efficiently in an increasingly competitive
environment. To account for this, the Commission should adopt a market-based
approach for granting incumbent local exchange carriers increased flexibility within
the constraints of an overall price cap.
A. The Commission Should Adopt a Prescriptive
Approach To Adjust Access Rate Levels.
(Paragraphs 218-40)
Frontier proposes that the Commission reduce access rates (including the
phase-out of the TIC) over the next two years.(20) The Commission should accomplish this by reinitializing PCIs on the basis of an appropriate measure of
long-run incremental cost plus a reasonable share of joint and common costs and
a reasonable, risk-adjusted return on investment.(21) Long-run incremental costs
represent the proper measure of incremental cost and, should therefore, be utilized
to set access rates.
To reset access rates to economic costs, the Commission should require
incumbent local exchange carriers to submit appropriate incremental cost studies
(including allocations of joint and common costs and return on investment) in the
next annual access tariff filing cycle and to reduce their PCIs by one-half of the
indicated difference between current PCI levels and the level indicated by the
studies. The remaining reduction should take place in the second annual access
tariff filing.
The annual access tariff filing cycle provides the most efficient procedural
vehicle for accomplishing access charge reductions. The process is already well-established, would provide all parties the opportunity to present cost data and
would provide the Commission an appropriate -- but not unduly lengthy -- period of
time to evaluate such evidence.(22)
The Commission's alternative proposals for adjusting access rates fail to
address the causes of uneconomic access rates. Altering the X-factor(23) would not
directly address the fact that access rates are currently above cost. This approach
would ultimately force access rates down, but only in a haphazard fashion. It is
preferable for the Commission to confront the issue directly, rather than through
indirection.
Similarly, readjusting the authorized rate of return or reinitializing PCIs to
target the currently-authorized rate of return(24) represent even more indirect
approaches. Cost of capital is only one component of the cost of access services
and, therefore, adjustments based solely on the cost of capital would not address
the other causes of uneconomic access rates.(25) Thus, this proposed approach
represents a partial solution at best.
The correct approach is for the Commission to reinitialize existing PCIs over
a short transition based upon economic cost evidence.
B. The Commission Should Adopt a Market-Based Approach to Pricing Flexibility.
(Paragraphs 161-217)
Although the Commission should not rely upon a market-based approach to
accomplish overall access charge reductions, it should utilize this approach for
pricing flexibility purposes within the constraint of an overall PCI.
The two-phase approach suggested by the Commission is generally correct,
although the Commission must exercise care with regard to the degree of pricing
flexibility afforded incumbent local exchange carriers. The Commission should also
place the burden squarely upon incumbent local exchange carriers to demonstrate
that the requisite competitive conditions have, in fact, been satisfied.
In the first phase, the Commission should permit geographic deaveraging of
access rate elements other than the SLC.(26) The Commission already permits such
deaveraging for special access and switched transport based upon a showing that
a particular study area is open to competition.(27) There is no reason not to extend
this flexibility to local switching.
The Commission, however, should react with caution to proposals to permit
contract pricing and volume and term discounts premised only upon a showing that
a market is open to competition or that some tiny fraction of customers are being
solicited by new competitors. At a minimum, the Commission should require
incumbent local exchange carriers rigorously to cost-justify any such proposals --
in addition to making the competitive check-list showing. A cautious approach is
necessary to prevent incumbent local exchange carriers from favoring the largest
interexchange carriers -- principally AT&T -- at the expense of their smaller rivals
for reasons unrelated to cost.
For similar reasons, the Commission should flatly prohibit -- at least during
Phase I -- incumbent local exchange carriers from offering growth-based discounts.
Allowing this type of flexibility could do no more than permit the Bell companies to
structure discount packages for which only their start-up in-region, interLATA
operations could qualify. The anti-competitive consequences of permitting such
flexibility are as obvious as they are undesirable.
In Phase II, the Commission should permit service category and basket
consolidation, as proposed.(28) In the presence of actual, substantial competition, the
additional pricing constraints engendered by the existence of baskets and service
categories would become unnecessary. Moreover, permitting this type of
consolidation would permit incumbent local exchange carriers to replicate pricing
conditions that currently exist in competitive markets.(29) Nonetheless, although the
Commission should permit rate element consolidation, it should do so on an
optional basis only. It should still require exchange carriers to offer access services
on an element-by-element basis. Unbundled access offerings are consistent with
the Act and will remain necessary to ensure that access customers remain able to
purchase only those access services that they require.
Again, the Commission should require rigorous proof from a requesting local
exchange carrier that substantial competition is actually present. In this regard, the
Commission should not repeat the mistake it made in the Expanded Interconnection
proceeding, of relying upon absolute numerical triggers(30) as a precondition for
increased pricing flexibility. Absolute triggers cannot take into account differences
in study area sizes.
Rather, the Commission should rely upon relative triggers, such as
percentage of capacity deployed or the extent to which specific geographic and
product markets are contestable and contested. Frontier agrees that the
Commission should evaluate such showings on a case-by-case basis.(31)
A combination of a prescriptive and a market-based approach to access
charge reform will best advance the Commission's goals of aligning access rates
with economic cost and affording incumbent local exchange carriers appropriate
pricing flexibility within the constraint of an overall PCI.
IV. THE COMMISSION SHOULD DECLINE TO TINKER
WITH THE EXISTING LOCAL SWITCHING AND
TRUNKING RATE ELEMENTS. (Paragraphs 71-95)
The Commission's proposals to unbundle further the existing local switching
and trunking rate elements(32) represents unbundling for its own sake without any
corresponding economic benefit. If the Commission eliminates the CCL and TIC
charges, it will have reduced existing access rate levels by nearly 20%. Although
additional uneconomic costs will remain, the Commission should address this
concern through prescriptive reductions in access rate levels. At some point, the
costs of additional, mandatory unbundling will exceed the benefits to be obtained
thereby. Such an approach would also run counter to conditions found in currently-competitive markets.
From the perspective of both incumbent local exchange carriers and
interstate access customers, the Commission's further unbundling proposals are
unwise. The costs to incumbent local exchange carriers to create the billing
systems necessary to accommodate the proposed additional rate elements are
likely to be substantial. Similarly, interstate access customers would be required
to develop systems to track and validate charges for the new elements. In the
absence of any indication that significant demand would exist for the new,
unbundled elements, the Commission should decline to mandate them.(33)
The evidence to date strongly suggests that further unbundling of access
rate elements on a mandatory basis is totally unnecessary. The Commission's
Open Network Architecture ("ONA") initiative(34) is a case in point. The Commission's
unbundling of access elements into basic serving arrangements ("BSAs") and basic
service elements ("BSEs") can be classified as throwing a party to which none of
the guests show up. Indeed, in the face of strong opposition from access
customers to the Commission's then-proposed mandatory ONA structure, the
Commission was forced to retreat and require the tariffing of BSAs and BSEs by the
Bell companies and GTE as optional alternatives to the standard access rate
elements.(35) Even now, demand for ONA-based services remains minimal. The
Commission should not repeat the same mistake here.
Moreover, evidence from comparable markets that are competitive today
suggests that -- at least on an optional basis -- less rather than more unbundling
is appropriate. In the interexchange business, for example, carrier-to-carrier
contracts are typically priced on a minutes-of-use basis with a few exceptions for
specialized services. A wholesale customer will typically buy minutes, not
individual rate elements.
On this basis, the Commission should leave the existing access rate
elements in place without further unbundling, at least until, if ever, the Commission
faces concrete evidence that further unbundling is warranted.
V. THE COMMISSION SHOULD ELIMINATE THE
ENHANCED SERVICES PROVIDER EXEMPTION FROM THE
ASSESSMENT OF INTERSTATE ACCESS CHARGES.
(Paragraphs 282-90)
The Commission's tentative conclusion that it should retain the current
enhanced services provider ("ESP") from interstate access charges(36) remains
misguided. At the outset, Frontier acknowledges that elimination of the exemption
is a decidedly second-best approach. The economically correct approach to the
treatment of enhanced services -- including Internet access -- is the adoption of
mandatory local measured service. Such a regime would recognize that increased
holding times occasioned by Internet access -- and the associated costs and overall
service quality issues -- are caused by end-users that choose to remain connected
to an information service for hours at a time. Only assigning the costs of such
usage to the cost-causers will create the proper economic incentives for efficient
network usage.(37) Such a regime, however, is obviously beyond the Commission's
jurisdiction to implement, as the vast majority of ESP access calls are intrastate in
nature.
Nonetheless, with respect to interstate calls, ESP usage creates identifiable
costs that currently go unrecovered. Although assessing ESPs interstate access
charges for this traffic is only a second-best solution, it is far preferable to the
existing regime, where all parties escape responsibility for such costs.
The Commission should correct this anomaly -- at least until a permanent
solution is developed -- by assessing interstate access charges upon ESPs,
including Internet access providers. Under this approach, at least some
responsible party is assessed the costs that are caused by interstate usage of
information services.
Moreover, the Commission's proposal to retain the current exemption ignores
history. The Commission adopted the current ESP exemption over twelve years
ago to protect a then-infant industry.(38) Once such special protections are in place,
there becomes a well-known tendency of infant industries never to grow up. The
fact is that the ESP industry has grown up. There is no longer any policy
justification -- if one ever existed -- for permitting ESPs (and, ultimately, their
customers) to off-load the costs that they cause upon other users of the public
switched network.
Conclusion
For the foregoing reasons, the Commission should act upon the proposals
contained in the Notice in the manner suggested herein.
Respectfully submitted,
__________________________
Michael J. Shortley, III
Attorney for Frontier Corporation
180 South Clinton Avenue
Rochester, New York 14646
(716) 777-1028
January 28, 1997
1. 1 Access Charge Reform, CC Dkt. 96-262, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Third
Report and Order, and Notice of Inquiry, FCC 96-488 (Dec. 24, 1996) ("Notice").
2. 2 Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act
of 1996, CC Dkt. 96-98, First Report and Order, FCC 96-325 (Aug. 8, 1996) ("Local
Competition First Report"), petitions for review pending sub nom. Iowa Utilities
Board v. FCC, No. 96-3321 (8th Cir.).
3. 3 Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Dkt. 86-282, Recommended
Decision, FCC 96J-3 (Nov. 8, 1996) ("Universal Service Recommended Decision").
4. 4 Notice, & 1.
5. 5 Id., & 6-11.
6. 6 Id., & 58.
7. 7 Universal Service Recommended Decision, & 776.
8. 8 The Commission requests comment on whether it should change the manner in
which it regulates terminating access. Notice, & 271. If the Commission eliminates
the CCL charge, this problem obviously disappears.
9. 9 As Frontier demonstrated in its Universal Service comments, the Commission
should strive to keep the federal universal fund at the minimum level necessary to
satisfy the Act's universal service requirements. See Federal-State Joint Board on
Universal Service, CC Dkt. 80-286, Comments of Frontier Corporation at 1-2 (Dec.
18, 1996).
10. 10 The Commission proposes to apply whatever rule modifications it adopts in this
proceeding to price-cap carriers. Notice, & 50. The Commission should, however,
distinguish non-rural price cap carriers from rural price-cap carriers. The
Commission distinguishes price-cap from rate-of-return-regulated carriers generally
on the basis of size and, therefore, the ability more readily to adapt to the proposed
changes and to emerging competition. Id., & 52. Smaller, price-cap-regulated
carriers -- such as Frontier's Tier 2 exchange carriers -- are more similarly situated
to rate-of-return-regulated rural carriers than they are to non-rural carriers,
particularly in terms of size and economies of scope and scale. The Commission
should treat the two comparably, by exempting all rural telephone companies
generally from the rules that the Commission adopts herein. This proposal is also
consistent with the Act in which Congress established differing treatment of rural
and non-rural incumbent local exchange carriers. The Commission should take
guidance from this distinction for purposes of access charge reform.
Nonetheless, such an exemption should not continue indefinitely. Rural exchange
carriers, although they represent a minor fraction of total access lines in service,
have by far the highest access rates in the country, generated in large part by
anomalies in the separations process (e.g., DEM weighting). Although not in the
context of this proceeding, the Commission must address the access charge levels
of rural telephone companies in the relatively near future.
11. 11 In addition, the Commission should index the unitary SLC to inflation. Indeed, had
the Commission adopted an indexed SLC in the first instance, the existence of a
below-cost residential and single-line business SLC would have disappeared by
now.
12. 12 Id., & 65.
The Commission also requests comment on how it should assess SLCs on ISDN
service and other derived channel services (id., & 69). The Commission should
distinguish those derived-channel technologies utilized to provide basic exchange
service (i.e., carrier systems) from ISDN and other advanced, derived-channel
services. In the former circumstance, the Commission should continue to permit
the assessment of the applicable SLC on each working telephone number,
regardless of the wireline loop technology used to provide dial-tone. There is no
reason for the Commission to distinguish among wireline technologies used to
provision a loop. Each end-user customer receives basic exchange service and
should be assessed a SLC.
With respect to ISDN, the Commission should adopt the suggestion of the
overwhelming of commenters on the issue (see id.) that is, it should assess only
one SLC on each pair, regardless of the number of channels that derived
technology will provide.
13. 13 The current CCL rules call for the National Exchange Carrier Association ("NECA")
to charge a nationwide averaged CCL rate. This rate is computed as the average
of the price cap carriers' rates. Any shortfall of NECA's revenue requirement is
then charged back to the non-NECA exchange carriers as long term support
("LTS"). Any reform that solely addresses the price cap carriers' rates will, absent
rule changes for NECA, have the effect of increasing the level of LTS paid by all
non-NECA exchange carriers. Whatever action the Commission takes to reform
price cap carriers' common line rates, it is essential that the rules for NECA be
changed in an appropriate manner at the same time.
14. 14 See Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, CC Dkt. 91-213, Report and Order and
Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 7 FCC Rcd. 7006 (1992), vacated sub
nom. Competitive Telecommunications Ass'n v. FCC, 87 F.3d 522 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
The Commission based the rates for the facilities-related elements in the trunking
basket on the basis of their special access counterparts, which the Commission
believed -- correctly, in Frontier's view -- were reasonably related to cost. See id.,
7 FCC Rcd. at 7028.
15. 15 See Notice, & 116.
16. 16 See Part III, infra.
17. 17 Because reallocation of costs between the interstate and intrastate jurisdictions will
likely be required, the Commission should promptly convene a Joint Board to
address these issues. The timing of the Joint Board's deliberations and decision
must necessarily coincide with the timetable for the proposed phase-out of the TIC.
18. 18 Notice, && 140-44,
19. 19 The Commission also requests comment on how to address embedded costs that
might go unrecovered in an economic-cost environment. Id., && 247-70. Other
than identifying and permitting the correction of cost misallocations and separations
anomalies, the Commission need not afford special treatment to these costs. First,
the credible evidence (id., && 249-55) suggests that the supposed problem is not
that great. Second, and more importantly, for large incumbent local exchange
carriers that elected price cap regulation, those carriers chose to divorce their rates
for interstate access services from the underlying costs of service in exchange for
the opportunity to achieve above-average rates of return. To the extent that there
are "public policy" costs embedded in current interstate access rates, the
Commission should ignore those costs incurred after price caps became effective.
Exchange carriers lobbied hard for price -- as opposed to cost-of-service --
regulation and should be held accountable for that decision. Thus, if the
Commission decides to address this issue, it should recognize only those "public
policy" costs incurred prior to the implementation of price cap regulation. Any post-price-cap deficit should -- as would be true in the case of an unregulated industry --
be written off.
20. 20 A short transition is essential to prevent inflated access rates from distorting
competition in the face of the advent of Bell company entry into the in-region,
interLATA business. See, e.g., Application of Ameritech Michigan Pursuant to
Section 271 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 To Provide In-Region,
InterLATA Services in Michigan (Jan 2, 1997). Access charges currently represent
close to one-half of an interexchange carrier's cost of doing business. A firm with
both exchange and interexchange operations will face the incremental cost of
access as its true cost of operating its interexchange business. An unaffiliated firm,
however, must pay whatever access rates are tariffed. To the extent those rates
are above economic costs, interexchange competition will be significantly distorted.
This distortion will provide the Bell companies' in-region, interexchange businesses
a substantial competitive edge and -- given the scope and ubiquity of the Bell
companies' exchange operations -- would have enormously detrimental effects on
interexchange competition as a whole. Such a result would be completely
inconsistent with the pro-competitive purposes of the Act.
21. 21 See Notice, && 221-22.
22. 22 During and after the transition to cost-based access rates, the Commission should
eliminate the X-factor component of the price cap formula. An X-factor adjustment
would double-count the adjustments that Frontier proposes. Moreover, once access
rates reach economic cost levels, there is no reason for the Commission to continue
to force access rates down.
23. 23 Id., && 232-33.
24. 24 Id., && 228-30.
25. 25 The appropriate cost of capital would represent one component of a properly-conducted incremental cost study.
26. 26 The Commission also inquires as to whether it should permit only decreases in the
SLC as a result of geographic deaveraging. Id.,& 180. The Commission should
decline to adopt this approach. For the reasons set forth in Part I, supra, the
residential and single-line business SLC needs to be increased, not decreased.
27. 27 Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company Facilities, CC Dkt. 91-141, Report and Order and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 7 FCC Rcd. 7454
(1992); Expanded Interconnection with Local Telephone Company Facilities, CC
Dkt. 91-141 (Phase I), Second Report and Order and Third Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 8 FCC Rcd. 7374 (1993) ("Expanded Interconnection Second Report").
28. 28 Notice, & 211.
29. 29 See Part IV, infra.
30. 30 Expanded Interconnection Second Report, 8 FCC Rcd. at 7423-25.
31. 31 Notice, & 205.
32. 32 Notice, && 71-91.
33. 33 The Commission should, in Phase II of the market-based approach, permit
incumbent local exchange carriers to create such elements on an optional, revenue-neutral basis. If demand -- in the face of a substantial competitive presence -- for
further unbundling exists, the Commission should not preclude exchange carriers
from responding to such demand. As discussed above (see supra at 15), the
Commission should continue to require incumbent local exchange carriers to offer
a baseline set of access rate elements that correspond to the current structure.
34. 34 See. e.g., Filing and Review of Open Network Architecture Plans, CC Dkt. 88-2
(Phase I), Memorandum Opinion and Order, 4 FCC Rcd. 1 (1988).
35. 35 See MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. FCC, 57 F.3d 1136 (D.C. Cir. 1995).
36. 36 Notice, && 282-90.
37. 37 This approach would recognize the economic truism that "a-minute-is-a-minute,"
regardless of the jurisdictional responsibility for a particular network connection.
38. 38 MTS and WATS Market Structure, CC Dkt. 78-72, Memorandum Opinion and
Order, 97 FCC 2d 682 (1984); Amendment of Part 69 of the Commission's Rules
Relating to Enhanced Services Providers, CC Dkt. 87-215, Order, 3 FCC Rcd. 2631
(1988).